Beware the Big-Government Right

 

Traditional conservatives and modern progressive intellectuals have had pointed, often bitter, debates in recent years over the future of American domestic policy. One of the major arenas in that struggle is the law of labor and employment. The left wants to toughen minimum wage and overtime laws, strengthen antidiscrimination laws, and promote diversity, affirmative action, and, increasingly, inclusive hiring. They also hope to restore unions to their pre-1970 glory days. The right opposes each of these initiatives by seeking to deregulate labor markets in order to let competitive forces increase overall productivity, indirectly benefitting workers through higher wages. My classical liberal credentials put me squarely on the conservative side of this debate.

Oren Cass, a senior fellow at the Manhattan Institute, has written a forceful and well-received book, The Once and Future Worker, which he hopes will change the terms of the debate.  He has also summarized his position at length in an article in the American Interest, titled The Working Hypothesis, to which I also refer.  Cass rejects the gospel of growth that is touted by traditional conservative economists, whom his book berates for insisting that things would be better “if only government had been smaller, with lower taxes and spending, and thus more room for economic dynamism.”  It then chides progressives for wishing that government had been bigger, “with more infrastructure investment, more checks on the market, a more generous safety net, and thus a prosperity widely shared.” In contrast to both, his bottom line is that “we can provide a subsidy for low-wage work, funded with higher tax rates and reduced transfer payments”, and thereafter “we can repurpose unions to help workers and employers optimize workplace conditions.”

Cass treats these as conservative arguments that “prize self-sufficiency, assign a central role to family and community and prefer the private ordering of markets to the centralized dictates of government.” But he refuses to go the whole way with libertarianism because of its blindness to other conditions that are needed for flourishing.  As a classical liberal, I think that his thesis is wrong on both the broad and narrow points.  I believe that insuperable obstacles stand in the path of this utopian vision.  First, the ends of the system are underspecified.  How much of a subsidy?  How high the taxes?  Who decides and when? And even if we could answer those questions, is there any way to reduce transfer payments that are made, for example, to the elderly and the disabled?  And can we do better if growth becomes weaker?  Next, the mechanics of transformation are underspecified as well. Cass makes frequent use of the dangerous royal “we.”  Unions are large and powerful organizations.  Just who will take the lead in their redesign, and who will be able to increase their membership from the under 7% today?

These concrete questions lead to a larger inquiry.  Why do we want to undertake this mission to be begin with, if its likely effect will be to reduce overall economic wealth?  For Cass, the answer starts at a theoretical level as he claims that it is wrong for economists and political scientists to rely on “the insidious metaphor of the ‘economic pie,’ which measures success by the amount of gross domestic product available to every American for consumption.” I confess that I am completely baffled why he rejects this traditional mode of analysis. The point of the pie metaphor is to help political and social institutions work to create positive-sum games from which everyone benefits. As Cass acknowledges, no one should complain that U.S. GDP is today three times what it was in 1975. Some portion of that GDP derives from scientific research, public education, and charitable activities, all of which would be compromised by lower growth rates.

So where’s the beef? For Cass, it comes in “decades of stagnant wages, a labor-force exodus, too many unstable families and crumbling communities.” He despairs over falling expectations because “half of Americans born in 1980 were earning less at age thirty than their parents did at their age.” Throw in an opioid crisis of recent origins and Cass perceives a social decay in a sea of economic plenty.

What Cass does not supply is an explanation of how growth makes American malaise more acute. His general laments about the state of American society sound awfully like the frequent jeremiads of Barack Obama, who bemoaned the lack of good jobs to help all the hard-working folks at home. Indeed, the claims of stagnant wages and low labor-market participation during the Obama years ring true, for his pious rhetoric was never matched by sensible programs on the ground. Indeed, there is a sense that Cass did not revise his argument in light of recent developments under the Trump presidency, flawed as it is on foreign trade and presidential decorum. As Michael Strain and James Pethokoukis point out, all the indicators to which Cass points on wage levels and job formation have turned upward, happily increasing opportunities for lower-income workers. Cass rightly insists that a solid employment market is essential for forming successful families and easing high levels of social anxiety and distrust. But it is a huge mistake to think that any program targeted toward low-income workers and their families is likely to work. The government needs to get out of the way, not to reform national character, optimize employment, or create some national purpose.

One clear illustration of how government is the problem and not the solution involves collective bargaining laws under the National Labor Relations Act (“the NLRA”). The NLRA was meant to create industrial peace and higher living standards for workers. It has done neither. Cass rightly attacks it for its “disastrous effects” in creating “hyper-adversarial relationships that neither side wants.” But he offers no alternative strategy to achieve his goals. I have long held that it is best to start over, by returning to the pre-NLRA policy which allows firms to announce in advance that they refuse to hire any worker with union affiliations. Critics moan that this hard-line position spells the end of worker participation in the firm. But in fact, the opposite is true. One little-noticed provision of the NLRA is Section 8(a)(2), which condemns as an “unfair labor practice” the formation of company unions, i.e. those that are organized and dominated by the firm itself. Labor unions demanded this prohibition to avoid competition from firms whose worker committees could, and did, give workers a chance to participate in formulating company policies, without posing the risk of strikes and the burdens of collective negotiation. The targeted legislative boost to union monopolies raises wages and lowers consumer welfare. It does not heal the collective soul. To better meet Cass’s goal, we need less regulation—and more growth.

Putting this stress on growth, moreover, does not denigrate the importance of caring for and assisting others. Indeed, one of the odd features of Cass’s work is that it uses a far too narrow definition of markets, which ignores the key role of private charity and philanthropic activities more generally. Of course, personal disabilities and natural catastrophes will persist no matter how much we preach the gospel of self-sufficiency. But massive government transfer payments are far from the best way to repair the social fabric. The government may be able to tax and spend, but it is hardly able to make sure that the assistance that is so desperately needed goes to the right recipients in the right form.

One term that has gone out of common usage is the old expression “imperfect obligation,” which stated that people in all walks of life should take care of those who need assistance as a matter of personal conscience and social obligation. This notion is a central part of the classical liberal tradition. That principle often plays out modestly, entailing such actions as providing food and other support for neighbors who have suffered injury—or sometimes less modestly, as in the provision of free or low-cost medical services to families of limited means, to the creation of large charitable hospitals and clinics to help sick and injured people without the means to pay.

These imperfect obligations were, by definition, not enforced legally. No one could sue anyone else for a lack of benevolence. But the absence of legal enforcement was– especially at the height of laissez-faire–the secret of their success. To keep these activities at a high pitch required the service of intermediate institutions—churches, clubs, fraternal organizations—to work. So it was that great hospitals like Sloan-Kettering, and great universities like the University of Chicago (Rockefeller), Johns Hopkins, and Stanford, were formed to fill that that social niche. Ironically, the rise of large government programs imposes taxes that drain support from these programs and increase the government role in transfer payments that only increase social dependence on government.

The bottom line, therefore, is this: Cass has a very restricted view of how a well-regulated economy works. No one conceives that GDP is the be-all-and-end-all of social life. But it is hard to imagine how all the sociological and psychological concerns that Cass stresses can be better solved with lower growth that makes fewer resources available to help human welfare. The single best measure of welfare is not wealth but life-expectancy. Cass and others are right to lament that it has fallen slightly in recent years. But it is even more critical to recognize that the greatest extensions in life expectancy all took place at the height of laissez-faire, increasing from about 40 years in 1850 to about 65 years in 1940. Long lives are highly correlated with subjective well-being and economic growth, and the one point that does not need empirical verification is that those gains cannot all be concentrated in the top one-percent. And so it is that the path to greater happiness and social cohesion lies in deregulation, not in some unspecified, new-fangled form of collective intervention.

© 2018 by the Board of Trustees of Leland Stanford Junior University

Published in Law, Literature
Like this post? Want to comment? Join Ricochet’s community of conservatives and be part of the conversation. Join Ricochet for Free.

There are 16 comments.

Become a member to join the conversation. Or sign in if you're already a member.
  1. RufusRJones Member
    RufusRJones
    @RufusRJones

    link

    …why Millennials might be unable to build wealth as quickly as those who came before.

    So, we have a group of workers who start out their careers in a bad labor market, brought on by more than 20 years of money-pumping by Volcker (later in his term), Greenspan, and Bernanke.

    But once those Millennials were able to get jobs, they then were faced with a world that was particularly hostile to saving, home purchases, and investment for lower-income workers.

    Our current situation is marked by endless monetary activism marked of near-zero interest rates and asset inflation which rewards those who already own assets, and have the means to access higher-risk investment instruments that offer higher yields.

    Meanwhile, banking regulations have been re-jiggered by federal politicians and regulators to favor established firms and the already-wealthy.

    Meanwhile, basic methods of saving, like savings accounts, offer interest rates that don’t even keep up with inflation.

    Combine this with rapidly climbing home prices, and we have a formula for an economic system where being an ordinary worker — who needs to build wealth from scratch — is facing low yields, less accessible debt, high housing prices, and lower incomes.

    Critical things like health insurance housing and education are bad values right now. Investing is too speculative because you can’t get any interest on cash.

    Wages are being forced down by globalized labor and robots, but the critical things just keep going up.

    They will never do anything about it.

    Our whole system of big government and global hegemony is based on an inflationist system, because you simply can’t tax increases in purchasing power you would get from robots and globalized trade.

    There are socialists in Minneapolis that think that old people should pay more taxes on their inflated house values with reverse mortgages  to equalize blah, blah, blah. I am not making that up.

    • #1
  2. Valiuth Member
    Valiuth
    @Valiuth

    Ever since I learned about it in my High School world civilizations class the Second Nobel truth of Buddhism has stuck to me as a deeply profound statement about the human condition. 

    “The source of suffering is desire.” 

    Our suffering is in large parts self inflicted upon us by our own perceptions and reactions. And not just everyday emotional suffering but also much of our feelings of economic suffering. The discrepancy between what we perceive we deserve and what we actually have. How many of our current economic problems could be fixed by an alteration of our expectations and perception? And to the extent that we realize that simply by changing our own desires we can eliminate our problems how real are those problems? 

    It seems to me that looking out upon our vast wealth and comfort we are discovering that money isn’t enough to satisfy us either personally or civilizationally. When we don’t have it we need it, when we have it isn’t ever enough. The problem though isn’t economic and so no economic schemes no matter how free market or big government they are can solve it. 

    • #2
  3. RufusRJones Member
    RufusRJones
    @RufusRJones

    Valiuth (View Comment):
    The problem though isn’t economic and so no economic schemes no matter how free market or big government they are can solve it. 

    I completely disagree with this. The government and special interests are clearly making many lives worse in an era of massive disruption from globalized trade and technology.

     

     

    • #3
  4. Bob Thompson Member
    Bob Thompson
    @BobThompson

    Valiuth (View Comment):

    “The source of suffering is desire.”

    I agree.

    Valiuth (View Comment):
    The problem though isn’t economic and so no economic schemes no matter how free market or big government they are can solve it.

    I agree.

    Individual freedom is what provides an opportunity for solving the problem but we are working hard to abandon any semblance of it.

    The solution is found in a process not a condition.

    • #4
  5. James Gawron Inactive
    James Gawron
    @JamesGawron

    Richard,

    I would say that Cass is dreaming. He expects a magical change in consciousness to somehow transform economic reality. This is the absurdity of all socialist ideologues of any stripe. However, his interest in Labor Unions is something that I share though not his so-called solution.

    To me, the problem of Labor Unions is the lack of a clear fundamental definition. Originally, as Labor Unions are a conspiracy in restraint of trade they were illegal. As part of the New Deal response to the Great Depression and wages below subsistence, private sector unions were legalized. As part of the wave of Great Society mania to improve life through big government, public sector unions were legalized.

    However, unions are still conspiracies in restraint of trade. Public sector unions are especially egregious as they will literally bankrupt a city (or soon a state) with their stranglehold. There is a simple solution to this. As unions are conspiracies in restraint of trade and the only justification for their existence is a wage rate so low that subsistence is impossible, unions are justified in only limited collective bargaining rights. Once the wage rate of union members is pushed passed an acceptable marker the union forfeits its ability to collectively bargain. After that, they are then using their illegal conspiracy power to extort unjust booty from their employer victims. Rewarding conspiracy is not a good economic policy or a good social policy. If we had got this right originally we could have saved this society an immense amount of damage.

    Regards,

    Jim

    • #5
  6. RufusRJones Member
    RufusRJones
    @RufusRJones

    James Gawron (View Comment):

    To me, the problem of Labor Unions is the lack of a clear fundamental definition. Originally, as Labor Unions are a conspiracy in restraint of trade they were illegal. As part of the New Deal response to the Great Depression and wages below subsistence, private sector unions were legalized. As part of the wave of Great Society mania of the , public sector unions were legalized.

    However, unions are still conspiracies in restraint of trade. Public sector unions are especially egregious as they will literally bankrupt a city (or soon a state) with their stranglehold. There is a simple solution to this. As unions are conspiracies in restraint of trade and the only justification for their existence is a wage rate so low that subsistence is impossible, unions are justified in only limited collective bargaining rights. Once the wage rate of union members is pushed passed an acceptable marker the union forfeits its ability to collectively bargain. After that, they are then using their illegal conspiracy power to extort unjust booty from their employer victims. Rewarding conspiracy is not a good economic policy or a good social policy. If we had got this right originally we could have saved this society an immense amount of damage.

    This is a very big deal. Their power is mostly artificial and gratuitous due to government laws in my opinion. I recently heard Tom Woods talking about this. 

    • #6
  7. TBA Coolidge
    TBA
    @RobtGilsdorf

    Valiuth (View Comment):

    Ever since I learned about it in my High School world civilizations class the Second Nobel truth of Buddhism has stuck to me as a deeply profound statement about the human condition.

    “The source of suffering is desire.”

    Our suffering is in large parts self inflicted upon us by our own perceptions and reactions. And not just everyday emotional suffering but also much of our feelings of economic suffering. The discrepancy between what we perceive we deserve and what we actually have. How many of our current economic problems could be fixed by an alteration of our expectations and perception? And to the extent that we realize that simply by changing our own desires we can eliminate our problems how real are those problems?

    It seems to me that looking out upon our vast wealth and comfort we are discovering that money isn’t enough to satisfy us either personally or civilizationally. When we don’t have it we need it, when we have it isn’t ever enough. The problem though isn’t economic and so no economic schemes no matter how free market or big government they are can solve it.

    Yo, we’re tryn’a do capitalism here you commie navel-gazer. Now get out there and start wanting stuff! 

    ;) 

    • #7
  8. TBA Coolidge
    TBA
    @RobtGilsdorf

    RufusRJones (View Comment):

    James Gawron (View Comment):

    To me, the problem of Labor Unions is the lack of a clear fundamental definition. Originally, as Labor Unions are a conspiracy in restraint of trade they were illegal. As part of the New Deal response to the Great Depression and wages below subsistence, private sector unions were legalized. As part of the wave of Great Society mania of the , public sector unions were legalized.

    However, unions are still conspiracies in restraint of trade. Public sector unions are especially egregious as they will literally bankrupt a city (or soon a state) with their stranglehold. There is a simple solution to this. As unions are conspiracies in restraint of trade and the only justification for their existence is a wage rate so low that subsistence is impossible, unions are justified in only limited collective bargaining rights. Once the wage rate of union members is pushed passed an acceptable marker the union forfeits its ability to collectively bargain. After that, they are then using their illegal conspiracy power to extort unjust booty from their employer victims. Rewarding conspiracy is not a good economic policy or a good social policy. If we had got this right originally we could have saved this society an immense amount of damage.

    This is a very big deal. Their power is mostly artificial and gratuitous due to government laws in my opinion. I recently heard Tom Woods talking about this.

    Perhaps someone (not me) should make a Union Bustin’ post. Ideally Member Feed in case of nascent genius. 

    • #8
  9. RufusRJones Member
    RufusRJones
    @RufusRJones

    Link

    Wellbeing is not about [objective] needs, but about being able to escape felt uneasiness.

     

    There is severe confusion about the meaning of #economicgrowth. Many seem to mistakenly think that it has to do with #GDP or producing stuff. It does not. Economic growth means that an economy’s ability to satisfy people’s wants, whatever they are–that is, to produce wellbeing–increases. 

    • #9
  10. TBA Coolidge
    TBA
    @RobtGilsdorf

    Government just wants to help. Really. It doesn’t much want to do the other stuff, the quotidian military/rights protection/Constitutiony stuff. Helping is fun. Helping is new laws, and ribbon-cutting in front of Buildings Named After Important People. 

    Government’s ‘No Job Too Small’ position coupled with its seizure of taxes to fund it’s ever-growing kindness mandate doesn’t merely eat up the very money people might (and did) use to help others; it also trains people to expect that it will be the source of all their aid while it works to eradicate (Little Sisters of the Poor) or at least ‘govern’ any NGO aid that might be, for lack of a better word, competition. 

    I could riff on ‘the Lord thy Gov is a jealous Gov’ and surveillance cameras for the Federal Task Force to Aid Fallen Sparrows, but the government isn’t a smiter.

    It’s a steamroller. 

    Once all the kinks are worked out – or flattened – it would be helpful for citizens to either go to work so the government can take their money or sign up for Eloi housing so the government can give them money. 

    • #10
  11. Chris Campion Coolidge
    Chris Campion
    @ChrisCampion

    RufusRJones (View Comment):

    link

    …why Millennials might be unable to build wealth as quickly as those who came before.

    So, we have a group of workers who start out their careers in a bad labor market, brought on by more than 20 years of money-pumping by Volcker (later in his term), Greenspan, and Bernanke.

    But once those Millennials were able to get jobs, they then were faced with a world that was particularly hostile to saving, home purchases, and investment for lower-income workers.

    Our current situation is marked by endless monetary activism marked of near-zero interest rates and asset inflation which rewards those who already own assets, and have the means to access higher-risk investment instruments that offer higher yields.

    Meanwhile, banking regulations have been re-jiggered by federal politicians and regulators to favor established firms and the already-wealthy.

    Meanwhile, basic methods of saving, like savings accounts, offer interest rates that don’t even keep up with inflation.

    Combine this with rapidly climbing home prices, and we have a formula for an economic system where being an ordinary worker — who needs to build wealth from scratch — is facing low yields, less accessible debt, high housing prices, and lower incomes.

    Critical things like health insurance housing and education are bad values right now. Investing is too speculative because you can’t get any interest on cash.

    Wages are being forced down by globalized labor and robots, but the critical things just keep going up.

    They will never do anything about it.

    Our whole system of big government and global hegemony is based on an inflationist system, because you simply can’t tax increases in purchasing power you would get from robots and globalized trade.

    There are socialists in Minneapolis that think that old people should pay more taxes on their inflated house values with reverse mortgages to equalize blah, blah, blah. I am not making that up.

    The italicized quote above is just patently false.  Home prices climb because there are buyers for the homes.  Millions of them.  So somehow, magically, people are paying mortgages on their new homes.

    Debt is entirely accessible.  Check your mailbox.  Lots of people are willing to give you some.

    Incomes are not lower.  That’s just false.

    I’ll put this comparison out there, as I have in the past:  I used to live in Vermont 4 years ago.  A buddy of mine (also from Vermont), who had moved to Charlotte, NC, a few years earlier, pinged me about a job.  That job, doing something extremely similar to what I was doing in Vermont, paid almost twice what I was making in Vermont.  Almost twice.  I couldn’t believe it.

    I moved to Charlotte and started the new job 3 weeks later.

    I bought a house in Charlotte 2.5 years after that.  A comparable house in Vermont would have cost almost double what it cost here in Charlotte.  Property taxes in Vermont would have easily been twice what they are here in Charlotte.

    Vermont is frequently advertised as a socialist paradise.  It is, for the economic illiterates who run for public office.  For the rest of the schlumps, it’s a burden of taxes, regulatory overhang, and a negative response to any new business growth that has essentially caused the state to begin its slow death spiral, where the fewer children that are born to native Vermonters stay in the state once they graduate from college, leaving it at a rate that makes it 1st place, in terms of states, as a place to leave.

    Compare NC’s business climate to Vermont’s and you’ll see exactly what’s wrong with all the hand-wringing about inequality, etc.  I have a huge secret to share with Ricochet.  Are you ready?

    Government creates and supports inequalities.  Politicians profit from this, in terms of buying votes.  Instead of fixing this problem, they make it worse, every year, with more laws, regulations, policies, and public grandstanding that exacerbate the underlying condition.

     

    • #11
  12. RufusRJones Member
    RufusRJones
    @RufusRJones

    Chris Campion (View Comment):
    The italicized quote above is just patently false.

    Those guys would say that home prices and apartment rents are rising excessively due to artificial stimulus from Fed policy and housing policy.  

    • #12
  13. Valiuth Member
    Valiuth
    @Valiuth

    TBA (View Comment):

    Yo, we’re tryn’a do capitalism here you commie navel-gazer. Now get out there and start wanting stuff! 

    ;) 

    Consumarism ho! It is Christmas after all. 

    • #13
  14. The Reticulator Member
    The Reticulator
    @TheReticulator

    Richard Epstein: But it is even more critical to recognize that the greatest extensions in life expectancy all took place at the height of laissez-faire, increasing from about 40 years in 1850 to about 65 years in 1940.

    Interesting that the author picked this particular 90 year time span. A historian I’ve been reading recently (Richard White) points to decreases in lifespan until the turn of the century. 

    The average life expectancy of a white man dropped from the 1790s until the last decade of the nineteenth century. A slight uptick at midcentury proved fleeting; nor was it certain that the smaller rise in 1890 would be permanent. A clear trend toward longer lifespans for white men was not visible until the turn of the century. It would be well into the twentieth century before white American men achieved the average lifespans of late eighteenth-century New England men. Black men lagged far behind. What this added up to was that an average white ten-year-old American boy in 1880, born at the beginning of the Gilded Age and living through it, could expect to die at age forty-eight. His height would be 5 feet, 5 inches. He would be shorter and have a briefer life than his Revolutionary forebears.

    Source: White, Richard. The Republic for Which It Stands: The United States during Reconstruction and the Gilded Age, 1865-1896 (Oxford History of the United States) (p. 478). Oxford University Press. Kindle Edition.

    And White points out that these data are not skewed by immigrants; the studies he cites were of native-born Americans.

     

    • #14
  15. The Reticulator Member
    The Reticulator
    @TheReticulator

    TBA (View Comment):
    I could riff on ‘the Lord thy Gov is a jealous Gov’ and surveillance cameras for the Federal Task Force to Aid Fallen Sparrows

    I steal.

    • #15
  16. TBA Coolidge
    TBA
    @RobtGilsdorf

    The Reticulator (View Comment):

    TBA (View Comment):
    I could riff on ‘the Lord thy Gov is a jealous Gov’ and surveillance cameras for the Federal Task Force to Aid Fallen Sparrows

    I steal.

    Please do. 

    • #16
Become a member to join the conversation. Or sign in if you're already a member.