High Court to Referee California Food Fight

 

This past week, the Supreme Court agreed to hear an appeal in an important case that could determine the structure of American interstate markets for years to come. National Pork Producers Council v. Ross involves a constitutional challenge to Proposition 12, a 2018 California referendum that requires all pork products sold in the state be prepared in facilities meeting California standards of animal health and safety, no matter where they are raised. As the plaintiffs explain in their brief, virtually all of the pork products (some 99.8 percent) sold in California come from out of state. On the flip side, California represents 13 percent of the national consumer market for pork products.

The requirements imposed under Proposition 12 are much more stringent than those in place virtually anywhere else in the country and, in the view of many farmers, are injurious to the health of the sow. Nonetheless, California insists

farmers provide each sow with 24 square feet of usable floor space and largely prohibits the use of individual stalls, even during the critical period between weaning and confirmation of pregnancy, when sows recover from the stress of giving birth, are bred, and then wait for the embryos to attach themselves to the uterine wall.

Given the complex processes for the production of pork products, it was undisputed that the only way to comply with the California law was to raise all hogs sold in the national market in conformity with the California standards, even when sold in other states. The net effect of the ordinance is to increase the cost of production by at least 9.2 percent, with a corresponding decrease in sales.

No one disputes that the state of California is entitled to impose these restrictions on any animals raised within the state of California. But it is hugely contested whether it can impose those restrictions extra-territorially and thus dictate the patterns of production nationwide. The Constitution does not contain any provision that explicitly and unambiguously addresses the ability of one state to impose its practices on others. The Commerce Clause states that Congress shall “have the power to regulate commerce . . . among the several states.” The hotly disputed question is to what extent that provision imposes limitations on how states can regulate those goods and services that are shipped in interstate commerce. These questions are answered by the dormant commerce clause jurisprudence, which has a long and confused pedigree. It addresses how states may impose restrictions that discriminate, on their face, against foreign commerce. And, more controversially, when state laws that are neutral on their face with respect to commerce, as is the case with Prop 12, but which have a disproportionate impact on out-of-state producers may apply. Both branches of the test rely on a “balancing test” that asks whether local interests in health and safety can justify a restriction notwithstanding the imposition of an otherwise impermissible burden on foreign commerce.

The unanimous decision below, authored by the highly regarded judge Sandra Ikuta, dutifully followed the current conventional line, which holds that the dormant commerce clause is valid only in the case of explicit discrimination—notably also applied by the Ninth Circuit to uphold a California statute that forbade the sale of foie gras within the state if it was produced from ducks or geese that had been force-fed, again, regardless of where those birds were raised and slaughtered. But, in one sense, the practical impact and interests at stake in National Pork make it likely that the Supreme Court will use the case to re-examine the scope of the dormant commerce clause doctrine.

Without a doubt, the nondiscrimination test provides a useful check on government power that in no way limits its ability to make legislation that it regards as best for its own citizens and residents. Thus, it is perfectly permissible to lower the speed limits for trucks on highways to prevent traffic accidents if the same limits apply to all trucks. But it creates a massive distortion in the competitive market if the state allows its own trucks to travel at 65 miles per hour but out-of-state vehicles must hew to a 55 mph restriction. It was surely one of the larger ambitions of the original constitutional design to create an open domestic market. The antidiscrimination rule (which looks at facial differences) offers a cheap and effective way to achieve that end. The simple point is that the state will now have strong incentives to pick the optimal speed limit, because the only way in which it can hurt the out-of-state trucks is to inflict an equal harm on local competitors.

However valuable that restriction, it falls short of reaching the ideal decisions in cases in which there is no local industry affected by the regulations in question—the situation here. The absence of local competitors removes local economic pressures disciplining the state’s political process, making it possible to target outsiders without hitting insiders. The hard judicial choice is this: does one allow California, in this instance, to impose unilateral restrictions with national implications? Or should the courts intervene in those cases in which the disproportionate impact makes the market distortions evident? Judge Ikuta took the former position by noting that regulations that “merely impose a higher cost on production” do not trigger the application of the dormant commerce clause, even where the state’s intention is to “influence” the business choices of firms operating outside the state.

The “merely” says it all, as the impacts here are huge and would have been knocked down under earlier law. Thus, the balancing test in Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc. (1970) stated a more generalized test: “Where the statute regulates evenhandedly to effectuate a legitimate local public interest, and its effects on interstate commerce are only incidental, it will be upheld unless the burden imposed on such commerce is clearly excessive in relation to the putative local benefits.” In that case, an Arizona official insisted that all crated cantaloupes grown in the state be packed inside Arizona, despite the fact that it was far cheaper (and just as safe) for a particular grower to pack cantaloupes at a nearer California location. The imbalance in Pike was so apparent that the court struck down that restriction on local producers. In National Pork, the stakes are far higher because a more onerous restriction applies to out-of-state firms.

In order to enforce Prop 12, California inspectors need to enter other states, because inspection of the products when sold in-state would provide no indication of the conditions under which they were produced. In order to justify these heavy burdens, an amicus brief prepared by Health Care Without Harm sought to defend the outcome by claiming that the state’s interest in the prevention of animal cruelty is sufficient to justify the imposition of these restraints given the “dire consequences for not only the health and welfare of the animals, but also for worker safety, food safety, and public health.” Without a doubt, California is fully within its rights to prevent the sale of infected products within its state. But there is no evidence whatsoever that any pork product sold within California has carried with it any diseases, and there is no reason to think that other states would be indifferent to these risks were they as substantial as claimed or even that the Congress would stand idly by.

Nor can this argument be salvaged by pointing to the deep moral and philosophical objections that many Californians have toward the practices of these pork processing companies—it is at best a makeweight argument. Any local offense against these practices applies equally to when pork products are both produced and sold inside and outside California. But it is insufficient to extend to the sale of goods neither produced nor consumed in California, a wholly non-local concern—yet that is the inevitable impact of Proposition 12. Moral objections by local citizens can largely be met by a labeling requirement that informs consumers whether or not the pork products sold in the state comply with California standards.

Disclosure has two advantages. First, it does not interfere with pork production elsewhere. Second, it does not prevent California residents who disagree with the California edict from freely purchasing—to say nothing of the citizens of other states— these products, as should be the case where there is no reason to have uniform rules for all market participants.

The traditional line—regulating the inherent characteristics of the product, which is permissible, and regulating the mode of its production, which is not—is neither mysterious nor abstract. It is easy to administer and will foster the preservation of the national market in goods and services, which is a constitutional, political, and economic imperative. What works for pigs, works for people. If National Pork is affirmed, could California now refuse to import any product manufactured by plants that hire workers for less than California’s minimum wage or do not have the same COVID vaccine requirements? Other states could chime in with different, and inconsistent, requirements. This proliferation will surely snarl national commerce, and will surely spill over into the export market as well.

Formally, Proposition 12 may allow other states to ignore California law, but its practical effect is precisely the opposite. Nondiscrimination principles do not guard against such territorial aggrandizement, which should never be allowed if practiced by one or more states. It is time for the Supreme Court to reverse the decline of the dormant commerce clause and prevent the national Balkanization of commerce.

© 2022 by the Board of Trustees of Leland Stanford Junior University.

Published in Law
Like this post? Want to comment? Join Ricochet’s community of conservatives and be part of the conversation. Join Ricochet for Free.

There are 24 comments.

Become a member to join the conversation. Or sign in if you're already a member.
  1. kedavis Coolidge
    kedavis
    @kedavis

    Pretty complicated discussion, but can’t it basically be settled by not sending pork products to the People’s Republic of California from other states?  I don’t see that PRC is “forcing” other states to follow their rules.  If they don’t want pork products from other states, they can’t have them.  Let the PRC residents take it up with their legislators.

    (And I wouldn’t be surprised if they end up importing pork from Mexico without following the rules, but that will be considered acceptable somehow.)

     

    • #1
  2. Skyler Coolidge
    Skyler
    @Skyler

    Richard Epstein: It addresses how states may impose restrictions that discriminate, on their face, against foreign commerce.

    For non-lawyers who would have no reason to know, “foreign” means from another US State.

    • #2
  3. kedavis Coolidge
    kedavis
    @kedavis

    • #3
  4. TBA Coolidge
    TBA
    @RobtGilsdorf

    I happen to live in CA. I hope to make a banned lightbulb run to Arizona later this month. Perhaps I should also stock up on bacon. 

    • #4
  5. Dr. Craniotomy Coolidge
    Dr. Craniotomy
    @Craniotomy

    I’m a californian.  I love this analysis.  I hate my state government.  

    • #5
  6. TBA Coolidge
    TBA
    @RobtGilsdorf

    Dr. Craniotomy (View Comment):

    I’m a californian. I love this analysis. I hate my state government.

    In fairness, wasn’t this a direct voter creation? 

    • #6
  7. Bryan G. Stephens Thatcher
    Bryan G. Stephens
    @BryanGStephens

    CA should not be allowed to force its standards on others. 

    I am all for their standards and I think that the people of CA can just go without pork. I think that the people of CA should pay, through their taxes, compensation for the lost revenue of the market of the pork they are banning. 

    That seems the most fair. 

     

    • #7
  8. Full Size Tabby Member
    Full Size Tabby
    @FullSizeTabby

    kedavis (View Comment):

    Pretty complicated discussion, but can’t it basically be settled by not sending pork products to the People’s Republic of California from other states? I don’t see that PRC is “forcing” other states to follow their rules. If they don’t want pork products from other states, they can’t have them. Let the PRC residents take it up with their legislators.

    (And I wouldn’t be surprised if they end up importing pork from Mexico without following the rules, but that will be considered acceptable somehow.)

     

    That would seem to me a clear solution. Pork producers refuse to adopt the California standards so that Californians cannot buy any pork. I suspect pork producers are really reluctant to abandon 13% of the U.S. market. My understanding from reading some of the legal arguments is that the pork market is so complicated (there are too many steps along the process from impregnating the sow to the appearance of the bacon from the sow’s piglet on the supermarket shelf) that unless you are willing to refuse to sell to California, there is no way to segregate California-bound pork from the rest of the market.  I understand part of the problem is that all pork passes through a very few national processors, making it difficult to segregate product flow to and from individual states. 

    • #8
  9. genferei Member
    genferei
    @genferei

    Richard Epstein: It was surely one of the larger ambitions of the original constitutional design to create an open domestic market.

    Really?

    This sort of snarl up is what happens when you invent stuff that isn’t actually in the Constitution, right? If other states get sick of California dictating what their pork producers do they can either directly regulate their producers or pass a constitutional amendment explicitly saying what they want to do about commerce between the states or do nothing and leave it to the market. The alternative is to invite judicial law-making. It might feel nice to stick it to California, but what is the limiting principle for this type of invention? Prof Epstein may be happy if everything is made subject to economic efficiency, but this is something else that isn’t in the constitution, and seems just as anachronistically arbitrary as ‘equity’ or ‘decolonialism’ or whatever the intellectual fashion of the day.

    • #9
  10. Skyler Coolidge
    Skyler
    @Skyler

    California has been doing this for decades. Car emission standards, safety standards, even the stupid labels on everything saying that the state of california has determined everything to be causing cancer.   Why would pig farmers suddenly think they are immune from the power of California?

    By the way, this mechanism that California uses to control consumer products and businesses is exactly what China is doing to the world.

    • #10
  11. Bryan G. Stephens Thatcher
    Bryan G. Stephens
    @BryanGStephens

    The real solution is to break up CA

    • #11
  12. kedavis Coolidge
    kedavis
    @kedavis

    genferei (View Comment):
    It might feel nice to stick it to California, but what is the limiting principle for this type of invention?

    As opposed to California sticking it to the rest of us, again?

    California just needs to be allowed to stick it to itself, for once.  If they want to say that pork from the rest of the country isn’t good enough for them, let them go without, instead of everyone else bending.  They also have the option of setting up their own pork production.

    • #12
  13. Nanocelt TheContrarian Member
    Nanocelt TheContrarian
    @NanoceltTheContrarian

    After Wicker v Filburn why would anyone assume that the SC would decide Constitutionally or rationally?

    Let the pork producers decide what they want to do. However much product they sell in California they can produce in compliance with California requirements. Whatever the higher costs are they can add to the price of their product. All of their competitors will have the same higher costs to sell product in California so market share should not decline for a given producer. The net effect is only that Californians will pay higher prices than the rest of us for pork. 
    I suspect that California will soon mandate that it’s citizens consume only a vegan diet. So this whole question is likely to soon be moot.

    • #13
  14. Dr. Craniotomy Coolidge
    Dr. Craniotomy
    @Craniotomy

    TBA (View Comment):

    Dr. Craniotomy (View Comment):

    I’m a californian. I love this analysis. I hate my state government.

    In fairness, wasn’t this a direct voter creation?

    Of course.  And I hate the referendum process here.  There’s a reason it wasn’t included in the federal constitution.  

    Frankly, I wouldn’t mind if pork producers just stopped selling to CA.  I love pork products but I feel that the CA voters need to see the horrific consequences our insane laws produce.  We are seeing that in SF & LA with the open air drug markets and surging crime.  We are seeing it with our skyrocketing gas & energy costs.  We are seeing it with the destruction of our public education system.

    Even CA voters are capable of backlash against the far-left.  We are starting to see it.  I’ve heard my long time progressive friends stating that they’re voting for any politician who is anti-woke, anti-mask, pro-school opening and pro-economic liberty.  

    Look at the utter failure of the CA single-payor bill and the landslide recall of the SF school board.  

    CA needs to hit rock bottom so that these progressive ideals will be derided for a generation.

    • #14
  15. kedavis Coolidge
    kedavis
    @kedavis

    Nanocelt TheContrarian (View Comment):

    After Wicker v Filburn why would anyone assume that the SC would decide Constitutionally or rationally?

    Let the pork producers decide what they want to do. However much product they sell in California they can produce in compliance with California requirements. Whatever the higher costs are they can add to the price of their product. All of their competitors will have the same higher costs to sell product in California so market share should not decline for a given producer. The net effect is only that Californians will pay higher prices than the rest of us for pork.
    I suspect that California will soon mandate that it’s citizens consume only a vegan diet. So this whole question is likely to soon be moot.

    Unfortunately, there’s no good way to insure that the pork producers don’t pass along the costs of PRC compliance to the rest of us too.

    • #15
  16. Full Size Tabby Member
    Full Size Tabby
    @FullSizeTabby

    kedavis (View Comment):

    Nanocelt TheContrarian (View Comment):

    After Wicker v Filburn why would anyone assume that the SC would decide Constitutionally or rationally?

    Let the pork producers decide what they want to do. However much product they sell in California they can produce in compliance with California requirements. Whatever the higher costs are they can add to the price of their product. All of their competitors will have the same higher costs to sell product in California so market share should not decline for a given producer. The net effect is only that Californians will pay higher prices than the rest of us for pork.
    I suspect that California will soon mandate that it’s citizens consume only a vegan diet. So this whole question is likely to soon be moot.

    Unfortunately, there’s no good way to insure that the pork producers don’t pass along the costs of PRC compliance to the rest of us too.

    According the the information supplied by pork producers in connection with this legal fight, there is no way for the pork producers to segregate pork production bound for California from pork bound for other states, so all pork produced throughout the United States will have to be produced according to California standards, and so yes the rest of the country will have to pay for California-level standards. Since the California standards have to do with the sows that are the mothers of the pigs that become pork, segregating California bound pork would require tracing a specific package of bacon back through a lot of stops: the packaging plant, the butcher, the slaughterhouse, the market from which the slaughterhouse buys the animal, possibly through a second market in which the farm that raises the animal buys the animal from the breeder, back to the breeder. 

    • #16
  17. kedavis Coolidge
    kedavis
    @kedavis

    Full Size Tabby (View Comment):

    kedavis (View Comment):

    Nanocelt TheContrarian (View Comment):

    After Wicker v Filburn why would anyone assume that the SC would decide Constitutionally or rationally?

    Let the pork producers decide what they want to do. However much product they sell in California they can produce in compliance with California requirements. Whatever the higher costs are they can add to the price of their product. All of their competitors will have the same higher costs to sell product in California so market share should not decline for a given producer. The net effect is only that Californians will pay higher prices than the rest of us for pork.
    I suspect that California will soon mandate that it’s citizens consume only a vegan diet. So this whole question is likely to soon be moot.

    Unfortunately, there’s no good way to insure that the pork producers don’t pass along the costs of PRC compliance to the rest of us too.

    According the the information supplied by pork producers in connection with this legal fight, there is no way for the pork producers to segregate pork production bound for California from pork bound for other states, so all pork produced throughout the United States will have to be produced according to California standards, and so yes the rest of the country will have to pay for California-level standards. Since the California standards have to do with the sows that are the mothers of the pigs that become pork, segregating California bound pork would require tracing a specific package of bacon back through a lot of stops: the packaging plant, the butcher, the slaughterhouse, the market from which the slaughterhouse buys the animal, possibly through a second market in which the farm that raises the animal buys the animal from the breeder, back to the breeder.

    Maybe they shouldn’t be too concerned with that small piece of the market.  Especially since, as I’ve heard it, pork production underwent a serious “collapse” due to covid etc, and so they wouldn’t be “losing” anything, just not gaining back quite as much.  That may not be a problem either if they’re having trouble getting workers anyway, the way many businesses are because of people who get more from unemployment than from wages, or just don’t feel like working.

    They really should just continue with business as usual, and if the People’s Republic of California doesn’t want it, tough.

    • #17
  18. Bryan G. Stephens Thatcher
    Bryan G. Stephens
    @BryanGStephens

    The solution is don’t sell to CA. I’d pay more for pork to make up the difference just to see bacon gone in CA.

    • #18
  19. kedavis Coolidge
    kedavis
    @kedavis

    Bryan G. Stephens (View Comment):

    The solution is don’t sell to CA. I’d pay more for pork to make up the difference just to see bacon gone in CA.

    Not just bacon.  They wouldn’t be able to sell Egg McMuffins, or Sausage McMuffins, or ANYTHING!

    • #19
  20. Bryan G. Stephens Thatcher
    Bryan G. Stephens
    @BryanGStephens

    kedavis (View Comment):

    Bryan G. Stephens (View Comment):

    The solution is don’t sell to CA. I’d pay more for pork to make up the difference just to see bacon gone in CA.

    Not just bacon. They wouldn’t be able to sell Egg McMuffins, or Sausage McMuffins, or ANYTHING!

     And their tears would be sweet sweet wine. California’s keep voting for this they deserve to be punished for their folly not make the rest of a suffer. 

    • #20
  21. Skyler Coolidge
    Skyler
    @Skyler

    Nanocelt TheContrarian (View Comment):
    Let the pork producers decide what they want to do

    The problem is that pork bellies have for centuries been pretty much like grain and other such products.  I can’t remember the word for it.  Pork needs to be bought and sold for all places.

    • #21
  22. kedavis Coolidge
    kedavis
    @kedavis

    Skyler (View Comment):

    Nanocelt TheContrarian (View Comment):
    Let the pork producers decide what they want to do

    The problem is that pork bellies have for centuries been pretty much like grain and other such products. I can’t remember the word for it. Pork needs to be bought and sold for all places.

    Commodities?

    • #22
  23. Skyler Coolidge
    Skyler
    @Skyler

    kedavis (View Comment):

    Skyler (View Comment):

    Nanocelt TheContrarian (View Comment):
    Let the pork producers decide what they want to do

    The problem is that pork bellies have for centuries been pretty much like grain and other such products. I can’t remember the word for it. Pork needs to be bought and sold for all places.

    Commodities?

    Yes, that is the word I was looking for. 

    • #23
  24. Darin Johnson Member
    Darin Johnson
    @user_648569

    What the pork producers will do is an interesting question.  It depends on the elasticity of demand for pork.  If the (estimated) 9% rise in cost results in, say, an 18% reduction in quantity demanded, then abandoning California would make sense.  On the other hand, if the cost increase results in, say, a 3% reduction in quantity demanded, the rest of us might end up eating humanely-raised pork whether we want to or not.

    Over time, pork producers will either get more efficient at producing California-style pork, or they’ll get better at segregating it. 

    California has been playing this game for a while.  Others have mentioned textbooks.  Cars is another area, though “California emissions” was sort of an option, I guess.  I would bet Washington and Oregon will pass similar legislation, making the leverage even higher. 

    • #24
Become a member to join the conversation. Or sign in if you're already a member.