Trump’s Flawed Protectionism

 

In the midst of the din over Charlottesville, let’s not overlook the Trump administration’s controversial stance on free trade. This smoldering problem has risen to the surface in the delicate negotiations that the United States now is undertaking with China over the status of American intellectual property rights, and with Mexico and Canada over the North American Free Trade Agreement. Before looking at the particulars of these two disputes, it is instructive to set out the intellectual case for free trade, which Trump has consistently misunderstood.

The basic insight here is that ordinary contracts between private parties are not neutral; they produce gains for each party. If I swap my horse for your cow, it is tempting, but wrong, to say that no value has been added for the parties because we have the same horse and cow after the transaction that we had before it. So why worry, the argument goes, if the trade does not take place? This facile argument ignores that these transactions are costly to complete. Why would two parties waste money to organize a trade from which neither side has gained? Even this simple trade is a positive-sum game that produces for each side a net advantage that exceeds the costs of putting the deal together. I could desperately need a cow for milk or breeding, and you might need the horse to pull a plow. The trade allows both of us to get greater value by the more efficient deployment of existing resources. That short-term advantage has long-term effects, by letting me breed horses while you breed cows.

But there is a catch. In general, bartering is inefficient because it is rare that any random pair has the goods that the other side wants in just the right amount. But introduce money, so that the sale of each animal no longer depends on the purchase of the other, and the gains from trade become ever more salient.

What applies to two individual traders can be easily generalized in two ways. The first is that trade makes sense no matter how many parties join together in a voluntary transaction. So long as each party subjectively values what it receives more than what it sells, the deal will create a social improvement for all the parties to it. Even better, the gains to the contracting parties open up opportunities for outsiders, a positive externality that it is all too easy to overlook. The second is that gains from trade among multiple parties also arise in the international arena, so that the reduction of tariffs and other import or export barriers will increase trade from which all nations will benefit.

It is true that free trade breeds competition and leads new innovative firms to displace old ones. But that is as much true in domestic markets as it is in foreign ones. Yet no one thinks that new competitors in domestic markets need a license from existing competitors to set up shop. The competition will benefit consumers with expanded choices, and it will help other firms by reducing the costs of their inputs. It will give all firms a strong incentive to keep up to date before the competition arises. Finally, it will place real pressure on domestic monopolies, including labor unions, to reform their internal operations before they lose out entirely. The great vice of Trump’s approach is that it treats trade as a zero-sum game in which American firms and American workers get ripped off by private companies—notwithstanding these positive systematic effects. But he doesn’t understand that the jobs that go overseas might well be lost in any event; domestic competitors can move in if the cost structure of incumbent firms is too high. Nor does he understand that workers who are presently unemployed could find jobs if both the export and the import markets expand.

This model makes it clear that there would be a genuine economic tragedy if special pleaders were able to derail NAFTA by pointing to some firm-specific or industry-specific loss. Those claims make no more sense today than they did nearly 90 years ago when they persuaded Herbert Hoover in 1930 to sign the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act that led to a vast contraction of international trade, which in turn helped pave the way for the rise of Nazi Germany in 1933.

We don’t want a repetition of that sorry episode. Of course, there have to be trade deficits between nations, but what of it? Right now, the balance of accounts with Mexico indicates that there is a total trade between the two countries of about $525 billion, with the United States running a trade deficit of about $63 billion dollars. But just think of what would happen if the Trump administration took the view that we were far better off with no trade and no deficit with Mexico. First, American firms would lose about $231 billion in foreign sales; American firms and consumers would also lose about $294 billion in purchases. And America generally would lose the $63 billion in foreign investment into the United States.

Each of these three pieces benefits the United States. Therefore, so does the package taken as a whole. Trump thinks that the trade deficit means that the United States has somehow lost in international trade. But he would never go so far as to say that other nations should shut down their trade with the United States because we run a trade surplus with them. In both domestic and international markets, we shouldn’t impose any external “fairness” constraint on the outcome of voluntary transactions.

The situation with China is far different, because the Chinese only pay lip service to free trade in setting their trade policy. Their chief misdeed is to engage in the widespread theft of intellectual property, which includes the theft of trade secrets, the infringement of patents, and the shipment of counterfeit goods into international markets. The second vice is that China often ties the entrance of American firms into the Chinese market to the willingness of those firms to share their intellectual property with their local Chinese partners who can, of course, use that property in unrelated transactions to obtain an illicit comparative advantage.

These classic hold-up games often lead to a major decline in trade. No state inside the United States is allowed to condition the entry of out-of state businesses into their market on the condition that they surrender intellectual property or agree to special taxes, or to sacrifice access to federal courts. The dominant nondiscrimination rule under the United States Constitution precludes the states from taking these one-sided actions. The result is that the domestic market is free from counterproductive trade wars among the states.

The hard question is what to do in response to outright theft and these illicit tie-in arrangements. Trump has threatened to initiate an enforcement action under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974 to unilaterally “impose trade sanctions on foreign countries that either violate trade agreements or engage in other unfair trade practices.” The problem here is that proceeding under this section puts the United States at risk of violating the World Trade Organization’s elaborate system of adjudication to sort these matters out. Stopping unilateral action cuts out the risk of abuse by home countries in favor of their own goods. But the flip side here is that it allows chronic abusers like the Chinese to string out proceedings, which in turn allows them to reap gains from their illicit practices for an indefinite period.

The Chinese insist that any sanctions from the Trump administration would lead to a trade war that neither side could win, given the certainty that the Chinese would retaliate in kind against any unilateral American action. But doing nothing is an implicit ratification of the status quo ante of China’s ongoing trade abuses. At the same time, the Trump administration needs China at the table to discuss its actions in the South China Sea and how best to contain North Korea.

It should be evident that the United States has no good choices in this second-best world, which is why it is so difficult to restore a regime of free trade once any nation decides to flout the basic norms. This is why it is all the more incumbent not to throw a monkey wrench into the NAFTA negotiations. One major trade showdown is quite enough.

© 2017 by the Board of Trustees of Leland Stanford Junior University

Published in Economics, Law
Like this post? Want to comment? Join Ricochet’s community of conservatives and be part of the conversation. Join Ricochet for Free.

There are 11 comments.

Become a member to join the conversation. Or sign in if you're already a member.
  1. EJHill Podcaster
    EJHill
    @EJHill

    Richard Epstein: The competition will benefit consumers with expanded choices, and it will help other firms by reducing the costs of their inputs.

    Dear Professor Epstein,

    How is moving domestic production of commercial production providing customers with expanded choices? The answer: It’s not.

    Mexico is not competing with the US in products, just labor. There are no Mexican car companies making Mexican designed cars. There are just Mexicans making cars designed elsewhere and used as a cheap labor Plantation.

    This canard of expanded choice is just that.

    • #1
  2. Randy Weivoda Moderator
    Randy Weivoda
    @RandyWeivoda

    Well said, Richard.  If we want American manufacturers to be more competitive with the rest of the world, the way forward is to cut regulations that make it difficult to make a profit here.

    As one example, on the campaign trail Donald Trump railed against Nabisco for closing a plant in Chicago and opening one in Mexico.  You don’t have to be a snack food insider to imagine the reasons why they did this.  Does anyone remember Hostess, who was in the same exact business and went bankrupt?  The people at Hostess said it was the labor unions that killed them.  Not predominantly because of the wages, but because of all the restrictions that decreased workplace flexibility.  And what was the city again where Nabisco closed a factory?  Oh yeah, Chicago, a city utterly dominated by labor unions.  Of course, we don’t want the federal government outlawing unions, but we don’t need a Department of Labor who always takes their side, like Obama’s was likely to do.

    Add to that, Americans pay more than the global price for sugar because we have a program in place to protect sugar beet producers from foreign competition.  So that’s another factor that makes it more expensive to make cookies in the U.S. than in Mexico.  Have I spent too much time thinking about the economics of baked treats?  Possibly.

    • #2
  3. Trinity Waters Member
    Trinity Waters
    @

    Richard Epstein: The problem here is that proceeding under this section puts the United States at risk of violating the World Trade Organization’s elaborate system of adjudication to sort these matters out.

    Letting their IP theft continue is somehow defensible?  Being pushovers is economically desirable?  Letting them continue their theft might induce them to conk the Norks for us?  Don’t see our motivation to play their games.

    The elaborate system, bureau-speak for interminably ineffective and unfair, is going to have whose interests at heart?  The WTO’s motivation surely isn’t America first.

    • #3
  4. Stina Member
    Stina
    @CM

    Richard Epstein: The hard question is what to do in response to outright theft and these illicit tie-in arrangements. Trump has threatened to initiate an enforcement action under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974 to unilaterally “impose trade sanctions on foreign countries that either violate trade agreements or engage in other unfair trade practices.” The problem here is that proceeding under this section puts the United States at risk of violating the World Trade Organization’s elaborate system of adjudication to sort these matters out. Stopping unilateral action cuts out the risk of abuse by home countries in favor of their own goods. But the flip side here is that it allows chronic abusers like the Chinese to string out proceedings, which in turn allows them to reap gains from their illicit practices for an indefinite period.

    How does the WTO trump our own laws?

    This is why “nationalist” vs. “globalist” isn’t just some isolationist or economic anti-free trade talk. Our laws take precedence for us. Subscribing to a World Government harms us.

    • #4
  5. Hang On Member
    Hang On
    @HangOn

    Trotting out the Smoot-Hawley shibboleth for the rise of Nazi Germany is a real howler. Anybody who believes that is irreparably damaged.

     

    • #5
  6. Jamie Lockett Member
    Jamie Lockett
    @JamieLockett

    EJHill (View Comment):

    Richard Epstein: The competition will benefit consumers with expanded choices, and it will help other firms by reducing the costs of their inputs.

    Dear Professor Epstein,

    How is moving domestic production of commercial production providing customers with expanded choices? The answer: It’s not.

    Mexico is not competing with the US in products, just labor. There are no Mexican car companies making Mexican designed cars. There are just Mexicans making cars designed elsewhere and used as a cheap labor Plantation.

    This canard of expanded choice is just that.

    It lowers the overall cost of products so that more choices become available to more people at lower price levels.

    • #6
  7. Jamie Lockett Member
    Jamie Lockett
    @JamieLockett

    Stina (View Comment):

    Richard Epstein: The hard question is what to do in response to outright theft and these illicit tie-in arrangements. Trump has threatened to initiate an enforcement action under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974 to unilaterally “impose trade sanctions on foreign countries that either violate trade agreements or engage in other unfair trade practices.” The problem here is that proceeding under this section puts the United States at risk of violating the World Trade Organization’s elaborate system of adjudication to sort these matters out. Stopping unilateral action cuts out the risk of abuse by home countries in favor of their own goods. But the flip side here is that it allows chronic abusers like the Chinese to string out proceedings, which in turn allows them to reap gains from their illicit practices for an indefinite period.

    How does the WTO trump our own laws?

    This is why “nationalist” vs. “globalist” isn’t just some isolationist or economic anti-free trade talk. Our laws take precedence for us. Subscribing to a World Government harms us.

    The WTO isn’t world government.

    • #7
  8. Stina Member
    Stina
    @CM

    Jamie Lockett (View Comment):

    Stina (View Comment):

    Richard Epstein: The hard question is what to do in response to outright theft and these illicit tie-in arrangements. Trump has threatened to initiate an enforcement action under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974 to unilaterally “impose trade sanctions on foreign countries that either violate trade agreements or engage in other unfair trade practices.” The problem here is that proceeding under this section puts the United States at risk of violating the World Trade Organization’s elaborate system of adjudication to sort these matters out. Stopping unilateral action cuts out the risk of abuse by home countries in favor of their own goods. But the flip side here is that it allows chronic abusers like the Chinese to string out proceedings, which in turn allows them to reap gains from their illicit practices for an indefinite period.

    How does the WTO trump our own laws?

    This is why “nationalist” vs. “globalist” isn’t just some isolationist or economic anti-free trade talk. Our laws take precedence for us. Subscribing to a World Government harms us.

    The WTO isn’t world government.

    if we submit our laws to its authority, it is in all but name.

    • #8
  9. Jamie Lockett Member
    Jamie Lockett
    @JamieLockett

    Stina (View Comment):

    Jamie Lockett (View Comment):

    Stina (View Comment):

    Richard Epstein: The hard question is what to do in response to outright theft and these illicit tie-in arrangements. Trump has threatened to initiate an enforcement action under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974 to unilaterally “impose trade sanctions on foreign countries that either violate trade agreements or engage in other unfair trade practices.” The problem here is that proceeding under this section puts the United States at risk of violating the World Trade Organization’s elaborate system of adjudication to sort these matters out. Stopping unilateral action cuts out the risk of abuse by home countries in favor of their own goods. But the flip side here is that it allows chronic abusers like the Chinese to string out proceedings, which in turn allows them to reap gains from their illicit practices for an indefinite period.

    How does the WTO trump our own laws?

    This is why “nationalist” vs. “globalist” isn’t just some isolationist or economic anti-free trade talk. Our laws take precedence for us. Subscribing to a World Government harms us.

    The WTO isn’t world government.

    if we submit our laws to its authority, it is in all but name.

    Are treaties world government?

    • #9
  10. Pete EE Member
    Pete EE
    @PeteEE

    Jamie Lockett (View Comment):

    Stina (View Comment):

    Jamie Lockett (View Comment):

    The WTO isn’t world government.

    if we submit our laws to its authority, it is in all but name.

    Are treaties world government?

    Treaties are world governance. They impose a system of laws that nations a their people are obliged to obey. Therefore, yes, they are the stuff that world government is made of.

    The difference is that individual governments are free to end treaties.

    • #10
  11. Jamie Lockett Member
    Jamie Lockett
    @JamieLockett

    So then you view all treaties as suspect or invalid in some way?  NATO? Versailles? All world government?

    • #11
Become a member to join the conversation. Or sign in if you're already a member.